|
The Unbundled Network Element Platform (UNE-P) is one
of today's most important avenues for local telephone
competition, and represents much of the growth in CLEC
line count since 1999. It is also the bullseye in the
cross-hairs of the ILEC's policy guns. No other form of
competiton is so troublesome to the ILECs. Is it really
the solution to the CLEC sector's problems, or is
something else afoot?
UNE-P is, in a nutshell, resale
of ILEC telephone service that is legally classified as
"facilities-based". The Telecom Act
specifically permits both "resale" and
"facilities-based" competition, but also
requires ILECs to make unbundled network elements (UNEs)
-- individual components of the network, delivered alone
or in combination, but priced a la carte --
available to CLECs. UNE-P is what happens when all of the
components needed to resell ILEC service are procured, by
the CLEC, as UNEs.
Total service resale is in decline
"Resale", or more specifically Total Service
Resale (TSR), is provided by ILECs to CLECs at a price
based on the "retail" tariff price, minus a
fixed percentage "discount" (typically in the
20-25% range). The CLEC is then responsible for billing
and collections. This doesn't leave much of a profit
margin for the CLEC.
A more serious question, though, is
"why?" Is resale truly competition? I suggest
it's not -- it's competition for the back office,
perhaps, but not for the service itself. The
"discount" is basically a sales commission. A
resale CLEC is a sales agent for the ILEC, not a
competitor. It's surprising, then, that ILECs even
complain about resale. The whole scheme was cooked up in
the first place by an ILEC (Rochester Telephone, who
called it the "Open Market Plan" in the 1980s);
their only real problem with it is the computation of the
commissions, er, discounts. Which, naturally, they always
wish were smaller.
Resale's value proposition, as it
were, is to permit companies to bundle local and long
distance service onto one bill. The customer thus saves
writing one check and one postage stamp. The reseller
gets account control. This of course hasn't caught on;
several early resellers, such as USN and Essential.com,
tanked. TSR is in decline, though it still represents
over two million lines. It's probably best for specialty
applications such as Centrex. The reseller can be the
company who provides the desktop telephones -- before the
Telecom Act, the ILECs paid commissions to these
companies, and TSR "discounts" are larger.
UNE-P and TELRIC pricing
Anything other than TSR is considered to be
"facilities-based" competition. CLECs don't
have to provide all of the facilities themselves. The
Telecom Act requires the major ILECs to provide CLECs
with any or all of the unbundled network elements needed
to provide telecommunications service, provided that the
elements meet certain market tests, which are left to the
FCC to determine. These are the "necessary" and
"impair" tests -- is access to these UNEs necessary
for competitors, and will denying them impair competition?
The Clinton-era FCC originally held that all network
elements used to provide basic telephone service met
those tests. Thus the UNE menu included local loops
(undeniably necessary for a wide range of retail
services), dedicated interoffice transmission (needed for
the CLEC to build a network out of the loops), operator
services, signaling (access to the Signaling System 7
network), and both tandem local switching (use of the
ILEC's central office switches). But court battles
prevented these from being available in combination
until 1998.
A CLEC can, of course, build its entire network from
scratch. Cable companies and the fiber-optic trenchers
have done just that. But it's frightfully
capital-intensive, and the non-cable players have been
financial disaster areas. CLECs can also make use of a
mix of their own facilities, such as switches, and the
ILECs', such as loops. But a CLEC can also order the
entire service in the form of combined UNEs. This mainly
differs from TSR in the way the ILEC wholesale prices are
set.
UNEs are priced, by law, without respect to the retail
tariff. This is a Good Thing, because retail tariff
pricing (which TSR is based on) is almost entirely
arbitrary. Local telephone company pricing is not based
on cost; it's an artifact of a monopoly era, when rates
were set by state regulators for political as much as
economic reasons.
UNEs are based instead on "forward-looking"
costs, using a complex FCC formula called TELRIC (Total
Element Long Run Incremental Cost). There are many
different ways to say what something "costs".
In the telephone world, it's possible to use direct
historical costs -- what did the network actually cost to
build? And it's possible to use "fully
distributed" costs, in which direct costs are
burdened by the common costs of running the company. Or
it's possible to use incremental costs -- what would an
additional unit of capacity cost to add? And those have
endless variations. TELRIC is a good compromise; it takes
into account modern (well, 1996-era) technology,
combining aspects of incremental and fully-distributed
costing. It's important to note that the TELRIC wholesale
prices charged to CLECs also include a profit margin for
the ILEC.
A funny thing happens when you compare TELRIC-based
pricing to retail tariffs. Some ILEC services turn out to
be much cheaper at retail! Rural residential service, for
instance, appears to be heavily subsidized -- TELRIC
rates for local loops in rural exchanges are generally
very costly, while retail rates tend to be lower than in
urban areas. On the other hand, urban retail rates are
usually well above TELRIC, by a considerably greater
margin than the TSR discount. So by ordering the whole
service as a set of UNEs, the CLEC can resell ILEC
service with higher margins. That's the main reason for
UNE-P, and why so many TSR lines have been converted to
UNE-P in recent years.
To the ILEC, this is just "tariff shopping",
as if that were a bad thing! But its implications go
beyond that. UNE-P is actually a valuable public policy
tool! In the short term, it's a tool for CLECs to gain
subscribers. It's also a way to undo a century of
mispricing of telephone services.
UNE-P allows the CLEC to set its own prices without
regard to ILEC tariffs. The CLEC can underprice the ILEC
for high-markup items like call waiting and caller ID.
The CLEC can offer flat-rate local service in
measured-rate areas, and can even leave off costly
"zone" usage charges that so many subscribers
find so annoying. UNE-P thus provides CLECs with a way to
provide service differentiation while still using the
ILEC's network.
Unlikely to last
The ILECs really, really don't like UNE-P. Neither
does their ally, current FCC Chairman Michael Powell.
UNE-P is already subject to some restrictions: In the top
50 market areas, ILECs can deny UNE-P for CLEC's business
subscribers with more than three lines, so long as the
ILECs also provide CLECs with the Enhanced Extended Loop
(EEL), a combination of local loop and interoffice
transmission. In the current round of UNE review, UNE-P
may be further restricted, or even phased out.
From a competitive point of view, this wouldn't be a
total disaster. It just isn't that hard for CLECs to
provide their own local switching nowadays. While a
1980s-vintage ILEC-style switch like a Nortel DMS-100 or
Lucent 5ESS is big and costly, newer switch vendors have
created a good selection of less-expensive compact
switching systems. And CLECs can share switches -- the
ILEC isn't the only one who can sell unbundled switching.
Most CLECs with switches have plenty of spare capacity,
so they can sell it to each other.
So CLECs who are committed to UNE-P should make hay
while the sun shines. It's a quick way to get going, and
it has the advantage of covering lots of turf. Worldcom's
MCI "The Neighborhood" used UNE-P to roll out a
new service to over a million subscribers in dozens of
states -- it would have taken years to set up on a UNE-L
basis. But I don't advise building a long-term CLEC
business plan around UNE-P.
But UNE-P's real value isn't to the CLEC community.
It's to the public, in forcing ILEC rates back into line
with costs. Because a CLEC can profitably use UNE-P to
create a cost-based service, the mere existence of UNE-P
creates a sort of unofficial cap on what an ILEC can
charge. Look at Ameritech's message-rated residential
services, for instance: They introduced flat rate
residential service only after UNE-P plans, such as The
Neighborhood, led the way. New York City is likewise a
mecca for UNE-P. Of course the ILECs will have to make up
for those revenues somewhere. UNE-P caps the implicit
cross-subsidies available to cover underpriced rural and
residential services. This too is not a bad thing --
explicit subsidies, competitively neutral, are the
appropriate way to handle high cost areas, and in a
competitive market, ILECs have no right to maintain
predatory pricing. It would thus be tragic for UNE-P to
be shut down before the ILECs were forced to rationalize
their rates.
|